Does Pancasila Economics Have a Relative in the History of Economic Thought?
Published: Wednesday, June 1st 2024
Published: Wednesday, June 1st 2024
Throughout history, economic thinkers have proposed a variety of ideas. These ideas can be seen
as stages, progressing from Mercantilism to classical liberalism, then socialism, and finally
Keynesianism. Each stage roughly corresponds to a major historical event: imperialism, the
Industrial Revolution, globalization, and the Great Depression. These economic philosophies are
like well-defined blueprints. They all have clear starting assumptions and use specific methods
to analyze economic issues.
Following World War I, and especially after World War II, new economic philosophies emerged.
Many of these, like Pancasila Economics, positioned themselves as "third ways" – alternatives to
both pure capitalism and socialism. A more prominent example is the Social Market Economy.
Developed in Germany during the interwar period, this economic model boasted a strong foundation
in academic theory. It heavily influenced the post-war development of both Germany and the
European Union.
In contrast, several other 'Third Way' models have emerged, notable for their apparent success
even without a deep academic foundation. These include the development models of the East Asian
Tigers (including China's Beijing Consensus) and the Rentier-State model employed by many Arab
states, especially those in the Gulf region.
The 16th century witnessed the rise of European empires alongside a distinct economic philosophy:
mercantilism. Thinkers like Sir Thomas Mun believed a nation's wealth grew through a constant
surplus of exports over imports, with gold and silver seen as the ultimate treasures. This focus
on accumulating bullion, as it's called, stands in stark contrast to the modern concept of
development, which prioritizes the well-being of citizens and their access to freedoms and
opportunities.
England, a dominant player, implemented mercantilist policies like the Navigation Acts, aiming
to control trade by requiring English ships for English goods. This directly challenged the
Dutch, who used to provide transportation services to English merchants as well, sparking the
Anglo-Dutch wars.
Across the English Channel, France had its own mercantilist champion: Jean-Baptiste Colbert,
Finance Minister under King Louis XIV. Colbert implemented a system known today as - surprise -
Colbertism. This aimed to maximize French wealth through strategic manipulation of tariffs and
taxes. High tariffs on foreign manufactured goods protected French producers, while low or no
tariffs on raw materials ensured a steady supply for their growing industries. Colbert
ultimately advocated for self-sufficiency in agriculture, a strong military, and the continuous
expansion of French colonies.
Colonies became crucial cogs in the mercantilist machine. European nations, including England,
France,the Netherlands, Spain and Portugal, established colonies to secure raw materials and
captive markets for their finished goods. This often took the form of the "triangular trade"
network, a dark stain on history. Resources in Africa and the Americas were ruthlessly
exploited, fueled by the abhorrent practice of slave labor.
While mercantilism sparked early economic prosperity, it wasn't built to last. The flood of
precious metals from exports triggered inflation for which David Hume provided the first
theoretical explanation, now known as the price-specie flow mechanism. It simply states that
export surpluses lead to an inflow of money (species), which pushes up inflation (prices).
Rising tea prices due to British inflation and the Tea Act, which gave the East India Company a
monopoly on tea sales in America, angered colonists. Boston merchants, who thrived on smuggled
tea, faced ruin if the market was flooded with cheap, legal tea. This threat to their profits,
coupled with resentment over the Tea Act as taxation without representation, fueled resistance.
The Boston Tea Party became the fiery response, a pivotal act leading to the American
Revolution.
As mercantilism thrived on exploitation, former colonized countries were looking for a
post-independent economic order that was different from that of their former colonial ruler,
even if they already adopted different philosophies as well and left imperialism behind them.
Adam Smith, initially a moral philosopher, is a key figure in classical economics alongside David
Ricardo. His moral philosophy challenged the Catholic Church’s long held tenet that private
property and economic competition undermines the formation of Christian values. In his first
famous book, "The Theory of Moral Sentiments," Smith yet explored how virtues like humility,
hard work, and respect for others are crucial for success in a competitive environment. These
ideas laid the groundwork for his economic views.
Later, in "The Wealth of Nations," Smith emphasized competition as a driver of economic growth.
He envisioned competition not as a brutal struggle for survival, but as a system that fosters
innovation and efficiency through equal access to markets. This concept of competition as a
level playing field became a hallmark of classical economics.
The decline of European dominance in the 18th century, coupled with the rise of newly
independent states, especially in the Americas, chipped away at the mercantilist system.
Advancements in transportation and communication made free trade more feasible, weakening the
zero-sum mentality (one nation gains, another loses) that underpinned mercantilism. This shift
paved the way for a positive-sum view of trade (both nations benefit), but a theoretical
explanation for the advantages of free trade was still missing. This crucial framework was
provided by David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage.The theory of comparative advantage
shows that if countries specialize in what they can do comparatively the best, free trade allows
countries to consume more than what each country could individually produce.
Yet free trade, while benefiting countries in aggregate terms, also creates winners and losers.
It is just that the winners win more than what the losers lose and it could well be that the
gains from free trade are concentrated among such few people that income inequality is on the
rise and with it, social instability. This is largely what happened in the global South, which
specialized during the first globalization wave between 1870 and 1914 in agricultural produce
which was concentrated among a small group of landowners to the disadvantage of many landless
peasants.
Many, especially in the global South, see therefore in the first globalization wave a de facto
continuation of the mercantilist exploitation system. Free trade, despite being an undeniable
win-win situation, had therefore very little appeal to many newly independent nation states,
including Indonesia.
Socialist thought posits an inherent societal division between the capitalist class
(bourgeoisie), who own the means of production, and the working class (proletariat), who sell
their labor. This inherent division, according to socialists, breeds inevitable class struggle.
The labor theory of value (LTV), while not exclusive to socialists, plays a crucial role in
their economic critique of capitalism. LTV proposes that the value of a good or service stems
from the amount of labor required to produce it. This focus on labor leads socialists to argue
that under capitalism, workers are exploited by capitalists. Since capitalists don't directly
contribute labor to production, their profits from selling worker-produced goods are seen as
unearned value.
However, most economists today reject the LTV, arguing that the value of a good is not
determined by the amount of labor it requires to produce it, but the intrinsic value it provides
to consumers. To make the point more clearly, if two miners are employed while one can mine an
ounce of gold with one hour of labor and the other one ounce of granite with one hour of labor,
the price of gold will still be much higher than an ounce of granite because it has a higher
intrinsic value to consumers.
According to socialists, an economy based on the collective ownership of the means of production
can eliminate the exploitation of workers. In such a system, the revenue generated from
collectively owned production would be distributed equally and therefore ensure a fairer
distribution of wealth than under capitalism.
However, critics argue that socialist economies lack a functioning price system. If everything
is owned by everyone, the value of something needs to be determined by some visible hand of a
central planner, as opposed to the invisible hand of the market. A central planner essentially
would have to ask every citizen, how much compensation do you require for an hour of work and
how much value you assign to each good? Assuming that the citizens are not at all that committed
to the idea of socialism, they would have an incentive to overstate their required compensation
and understate the values of the goods produced in order to get the greatest net benefit. This
would then necessarily cause the central planner to work with inflated costs and deflated real
prices, which inevitably will lead to shortages once the goods are produced. Aware of the
challenge self-interest poses to socialist economies, socialists implemented measures like
propaganda, cultural revolutions, and neighborhood watch committees.
In sum, despite theoretical and practical concerns about a socialist economy's functionality,
the promise of a more just system seemed to outweigh the risks. This was particularly true for
newly independent nations that lived through colonial exploitation.
The Great Depression was a crucible that forged John Maynard Keynes' economic theories. As
markets spiraled downward following the 1929 Stock Market crash, mass unemployment gripped
economies worldwide. Businesses, saddled with excess capacity (factories equipped to produce far
more than what was being demanded), faced a stark reality – a demand, not a supply, problem.
Traditional economic thought, rooted in laissez-faire principles, viewed such crises as
self-correcting. Lower wages, according to this logic, would eventually entice businesses to
re-hire workers, restoring full employment. But Keynes famously quipped, "In the long run, we
are all dead." He argued for immediate intervention to address the short-term crisis.
Keynesian economics, in contrast to classical economics (focused on long-term supply-side
factors), emphasizes short-term demand-side solutions. Through government policies aimed at
stabilizing aggregate demand, economies could utilize existing capacity and reduce unemployment.
Keynes proposed two main tools: fiscal and monetary policy. Fiscal policy involves government
spending on public projects, creating jobs and injecting income into the economy. Workers, with
this newfound income, would then purchase goods and services, stimulating further economic
activity. Monetary policy, on the other hand, focuses on lowering interest rates, incentivizing
businesses to invest and expand production.
In the context of the Great Depression, Keynes believed monetary policy was ineffective. With
factories underutilized, businesses had little reason to borrow, even at lower rates. This
situation, known as a liquidity trap, rendered monetary policy useless. Keynes argued for fiscal
policy whenever demand falls short of what existing capacity could produce, and monetary policy
when existing income could support higher demand.
While Keynesian economics holds strong theoretical appeal, it's not without its detractors. The
Austrian Business Cycle Theory, championed by Friedrich Hayek and later adopted by Milton
Friedman's monetarism, argues that the Great Depression could have been prevented through a
stable money supply. The rapid expansion of the money supply in the 1920s, followed by a sharp
contraction, is seen as the culprit – artificially low interest rates fueled an investment
bubble that ultimately burst.
Another critique comes from Joseph Schumpeter, who argued that government intervention can
stifle innovation. Fiscal policy financed by borrowing, according to Schumpeter, drives up
interest rates, hindering private investment and the crucial role it plays in economic growth.
Schumpeter believed innovation and private initiative, not government spending, is the key to
economic recovery.
Keynesian economics may not be a comprehensive economic philosophy, but it revolutionized how
economists view short-run crisis management. Its place in history is undeniable. It was the
first major school of thought to challenge the dominant laissez-faire approach, recognizing that
a healthy economy requires more than just private property and competition. Keynesian thought
introduced the crucial role of the state in stabilizing the economy, particularly during
downturns.It was this insight that caused other philosophies to emerge as “third ways.”
The Social Market Economy (SME) stands as a powerful alternative to the extremes of unbridled
capitalism and centralized planning. Developed in Germany after World War II, the SME emerged
from a deep reflection on economic history. Its vast literature dissects past successes and
failures, aiming to forge a better path.
At the heart of the SME lie two distinct, yet complementary, schools of thought. The Cologne
School draws on economic humanism, recognizing that individuals seek both economic freedom and
social responsibility. Economic humanism is also heavily influenced by Christian Social Ethics.
The Freiburg School, on the other hand, emphasizes ordoliberalism, the importance of
establishing a legal and institutional framework (Ordnungspolitik) to ensure a level competitive
playing field and promote equitable social development within a market economy.
The Social Market Economy (SME) stands apart from both laissez-faire capitalism and socialism.
This distinctiveness is evident in how each system views economic actors and the path to
economic justice within a free market.
While all three acknowledge equal opportunity as a fundamental right, their beliefs on its
achievability within a free market diverge. Laissez-faire capitalism holds that the free market
inherently provides equal opportunity, while socialism argues the opposite, pointing to inherent
inequalities it creates. The SME takes a middle ground, recognizing the limitations of the free
market in fostering a level playing field.
The most significant difference lies in the role of the state. Laissez-faire advocates for
minimal government intervention, believing the market self-regulates best. Socialists, on the
other hand, favor state control to achieve economic justice, often through centralized planning.
The SME takes a pragmatic approach. It promotes competition by fostering equal opportunity
through public investments in, for example, education and social safety nets, as well as the
regulation of markets.
Imagine a race. Laissez-faire economics is like letting everyone run without any rules. Social
market economics, on the other hand, sets clear guidelines (order policy) for the race. This
ensures a fair competition where the fastest runner wins, not the one who elbows their way to
the front. While laissez-faire might eventually correct imbalances, social market economics aims
to prevent them from happening in the first place. Likewise, social market economists see in
public education and mandatory participation in health care and social safety nets competition
enhancing institutions, not any kind of socialism as laissez-faire adherents might call it.
It's important to remember that the labels of laissez-faire, socialism, and social market
economy represent ideals, not rigid categories. In the real world, most economies are a blend,
incorporating elements of both markets and central planning. For instance, the US might see
itself as a free market, Germany a social market economy, and China a socialist economy. But in
reality, they all exist on a spectrum – a mixed economy with a unique mix of market forces and
government intervention. The key question isn't which label perfectly applies, but rather why
some mixed economies thrive while others struggle. What makes a successful mix, and what
imbalances need adjustment, are the crucial considerations.
Beyond these core models, numerous development strategies exist. Two prominent ones are
export-led growth and import-substitution. However, rather than representing complete
development models, these strategies highlight a central focus. For instance,
import-substitution aligns closely with socialist principles, while export-led growth is more
akin to liberalism.
Countries like the East Asian Tigers (Hong Kong, South Korea, Singapore, and Taiwan) exemplify
export-led growth. Interestingly, even some self-proclaimed socialist nations like China and
Vietnam are adopting this approach. Conversely, import-substitution was popular in Latin
America.
The choice between these approaches wasn't always a product of deliberate national planning.
Geopolitical realities played a significant role, especially for the East Asian Tigers. Consider
their situations: Hong Kong was a British colony, South Korea was the capitalist half of a
divided nation, Taiwan is claimed by China, and Singapore, after being expelled from Malaysia,
lacked the resources for a closed economy.
The Cold War significantly shaped the environment for the rise of the East Asian Tigers. As the
sole global superpower, the United States aimed to mold the post-WWII world and prevent the
spread of communism. Building allies became a cornerstone of this strategy, achieved in part
through generous aid programs like the Marshall Plan for Europe. While South Korea and Taiwan
lacked a similarly named program, they too received substantial US grants.
Furthermore, the US spearheaded the creation of a free-trade-based world economic order. Given
the Cold War tensions in East Asia, partnering with the West under US leadership appeared as the
most promising development path for these nations.
Unlike East Asia, export-led growth held less appeal for many Latin American countries. During
the first wave of globalization, trade primarily enriched the landowning elite in the global
South, contrasting with the rise of industrialists in the global North. The industrial
revolution eventually led to the political decline of these landed elites in the North. However,
in Latin America, the lack of a significant industrial sector prevented a similar
transformation, hindering political liberalization.
In the post-WWII era, as industrialization emerged as the key to development, many Latin
American countries felt pressure to catch up. Import-substitution appeared to be the only viable
path. In contrast, the East Asian Tigers, starting with war-ravaged economies, minimal industry,
and no entrenched elites, benefitted from export-led growth fueled by foreign investment.
However, in Latin America, largely unscathed by the war, outward-orientation and foreign
investment would have been politically risky for established elites.
The resource-rich nations of the Gulf Cooperation Council (GCC) - Bahrain, Kuwait, Oman, Qatar,
Saudi Arabia, and the United Arab Emirates - offer another noteworthy development experience.
However, their unique economic foundation based on natural resources makes it difficult to
directly replicate their model in other countries, especially as related to the financing of
development.
Despite the various differences between outward-oriented, import-substituting, and natural
resource rich modernizing economies, they nevertheless share one communality: A proactive role
of the state. Proactivity of the state in the development literature is known as Big Push
theories, of which there are two branches: Balanced and unbalanced growth strategists.
Balanced growth strategists highlight the "poverty trap" - a vicious cycle where low income
leads to low savings, hindering investment and perpetuating poverty. They argue that government
intervention is crucial to break this cycle.
A key aspect of balanced growth is avoiding uneven development. For instance, rapid
industrialization shouldn't come at the expense of agriculture, which could lead to food
shortages. Therefore, balanced growth strategies advocate for government planning to ensure all
sectors (industry, agriculture, infrastructure) develop at a similar pace.
Unbalanced growth proponents, in contrast to balanced growth advocates, don't believe in the
poverty trap. They argue for a different vicious cycle: "entrepreneurial disorientation." Here,
the lack of clear market signals discourages investment, which in turn hinders growth. Their
solution? Deliberately unbalance the economy.
This strategy focuses on prioritizing specific sectors with significant ripple effects, known as
"commanding heights." These include energy, steel, infrastructure, education, and public health.
By jumpstarting these sectors, unbalanced growth aims to awaken dormant entrepreneurial spirit
and stimulate overall growth.
Comparing these strategies, balanced growth focuses on the supply side of the economy, ensuring
resources and capabilities are available across sectors. Conversely, unbalanced growth
prioritizes the demand side, stimulating specific sectors to drive overall growth.
East Asia's success, often attributed to a combination of outward orientation and unbalanced
growth strategies, finds echoes in the rapid modernization of the Arab Gulf States. However,
India's post-independence focus on balanced growth presents a contrasting case.
The key to understanding the East Asian advantage lies in the way they utilized public
investments. When coupled with outward orientation, these investments created a "market test."
Failures were exposed early on the global stage, allowing for swift course correction.
Additionally, East Asian economies thrived on private enterprise.
Latin America, despite pursuing seemingly similar industrialization under unbalanced growth
principles, fell short. Their reliance on import-substitution shielded them from the "market
test." Mistakes remained hidden, hindering timely adjustments. Furthermore, state-controlled
economies prioritized actors with closer ties to the government, dampening market forces.
Our exploration of development models suggests surprising parallels between Pancasila Economics
and social market economics. These similarities are most striking when we consider their core
objectives. Both prioritize achieving equitable social development, explicitly emphasizing the
need for economic systems that foster fairness and opportunity for all.
Indonesia's Constitution (Articles 33 & 34) hints at socialist undertones, potentially
contrasting Pancasila Economics with social market economies. However, Mubyarto's resistance to
Sukarno's centralized planning and Suharto's top-down liberalization suggest an openness to a
social market approach. This begs the question: How closely does social market economic thought
align with Pancasila Economic principles?
It's important to emphasize that this comparison isn't meant to replace Pancasila Economics with
social market economic ideas. Instead, it aims to reinvigorate discussions surrounding Pancasila
Economics by drawing parallels with a like-minded economic tradition. Both systems,
interestingly enough, challenge the extremes of pure capitalism and socialism. They share
fundamental questions about the fit between these dominant philosophies and common conceptions
of humanity, universal notions of justice, and the role of the state in upholding these ideals.