Pancasila Economics - Where does it stand?
Published: Wednesday, June 1st 2024
Published: Wednesday, June 1st 2024
The idea of Pancasila Economics is unique in the history of economic thought. Eventually, not
many
countries can pride themselves with the development of a distinct national economic model
motivated
by a country’s very specific historical and cultural context. For comparison, both classical
economic liberalism and socialism were not developed as country-specific concepts. Rather, they
used, and abused, national experiences as strawmen for the development of seemingly universal
philosophies. Pancasila Economics was always supposed to be rooted in Indonesia’s specific
historical and cultural context to serve Indonesia.
The Pancasila state ideology can be thought of as Indonesia’s normative compass, supposed to
show
the economic system its direction. Unfortunately, the compass’s needle has been wildly spinning
since independence. Sukarno’s “Old Order” and Suharto’s “New Order” each gave Pancasila a very
different political interpretation, leaving Pancasila economics regularly in troubled waters.
Liddle (1982, p. 96) notes that if a widely accepted set of ideas lacks clear specifics,
politicians
with their own agendas will try to frame their values as the true essence or authentic
interpretation of the dominant ideology. This is exemplified by Suharto’s Demokrasi Pancasila,
where
he so tightly linked his policies to Pancasila that there was little space for debate about what
it
truly meant. In contrast, Pancasila Economics remains more open-ended. The government has not
attempted to attach a specific ideology to its economic policies, allowing for a wider
discussion.
This statement regarding the state of Pancasila Economic research seems still widely true even
today.
According to Liddle (1982), Pancasila Economics has two major interpretations. Chronologically,
these are (1) the Sukarno-influenced anti-capitalist and nationalist, (2) the Suharto-influenced
Bappenas (standing for Badan Perencanaan Pembangunan Nasional, Ministry of National Development
Planning). The Sukarno-influenced anti-capitalist and nationalist perspective emphasized the
“common
endeavor” of Article 33 of the constitution, promoting cooperatives, central-planning, a focus
on
basic needs, and restrictions on foreign ownership. Bappenas technocrats under Suharto argued
for a
state-regulated private enterprise system, seeking a middle way between a completely free market
and
a command economy, with both market elements and government planning, skepticism of
cooperatives,
and more openness towards foreign capital.
Within Pancasila Economic thought, Professor Dr. Mubyarto stands out as a towering figure in the
development of Pancasila economic thought. His intellectual journey began at Gadjah Mada
University
in Indonesia, where he honed his economic foundation. He then broadened his horizons by pursuing
graduate degrees in the United States, a Master's from Vanderbilt University and a PhD from Iowa
State University. Returning to Indonesia, Mubyarto rejoined his alma mater, Gadjah Mada
University,
where he took the helm of the Center for Pancasila Economic Studies. His influence, however,
extended far beyond the academic realm. Mubyarto actively served as a trusted advisor to the
Indonesian government, offering his expertise to shape the nation's economic landscape.
Mubyarto humbly rejected the title of "founding father" of Pancasila Economics. He saw himself
as a
torchbearer, carrying forward the ideals enshrined in Indonesia's constitution, Pancasila. These
ideals, championed by Indonesia's founding fathers, President Soekarno and Vice President
Mohammad
Hatta, expressed skepticism towards unfettered capitalism (laissez-faire). Both leaders
envisioned a
system that blended central planning with decentralized implementation through cooperatives.
This,
they believed, was the key to achieving the goals outlined in Pancasila, particularly principles
like achieving a "civilized" (Principle 2), "just" (Principle 5), and "democratic" (Principle 4)
society. Central planning, in their eyes, offered a mechanism to address emerging social
inequalities, a safeguard absent in laissez-faire capitalism. The combination of central
planning
with decentralized implementation, they argued, ensured everyone had a voice, fostering a
democratic
society.
However, this framework did not explicitly address the principle of "unity" (Principle 3). Here,
Mubyarto carved his own legacy. He believed Indonesia's true challenge to unity wasn't its
diverse
tapestry of ethnicities, languages, and religions. Mubyarto, like Soekarno and Hatta, firmly
embraced secularism. Instead, the chasm between the living standards of urban and rural areas
posed
the greater threat. Mubyarto questioned the central government's ability to effectively address
the
needs of rural communities through top-down planning alone. This critique, documented by Dick
and
McCawley in 2005, offers valuable insight. The authors reference his 1968 lament regarding
Jakarta's
lack of understanding and competence in fostering rural development. The timing of this
critique,
coinciding with the end of the Soekarno era, suggests Mubyarto held reservations about
Soekarno's
economic policies, despite agreeing with the Pancasila ideals.
Mubyarto's disillusionment further deepened with the economic policies of Suharto's New Order,
particularly "the top-down, materialistic and pro-market policies" implemented during that
period.
Therefore, ascribing purely socialist leanings to Mubyarto would be a mischaracterization of his
true development agenda. His advocacy for collaborative decision-making within small
cooperatives
doesn't equate to traditional socialism. After all, cooperatives are commonplace in market
economies, especially in rural areas. Similarly, attributing a fondness for Suharto-style
capitalism
to Mubyarto falls short. For Mubyarto, Pancasila economics was supposed to be a practical and
implementable ‘Third Way,’ not an enslavement to any economic ideology.
So what characteristics best describe Mubyarto's Pancasila Economics? McCawley (1982) summarizes
its
main features in five key points:
(1) The “role of state enterprises and especially of cooperatives would be important. In sectors
where
these institutions could not operate efficiently, private enterprise would be permitted to have
the
major role. In all sectors economic enterprises would be expected to operate on “harmonious and
family principles” (asas kekeluargan dan prinsip harmoni), and not on the basis of conflicting
personal interests.”
(2) “In contrast to the capitalist system where (it is alleged) economic incentives are designed
to
motivate selfish and individualistic “economic man”, in a Pancasila economy incentives would
operate
on the basis of social and religious values as well as economic ones. In other words, “higher
motives” would be encouraged rather than simply relying on the “lower motives” which underpin
the
operations of capitalist societies.
(3) “Egalitarian principles supporting greater social equality would be given high priority.”
(4) “The creation of a “strong national economy” (perekonomian nasional yang tangguh) is seen as
important. A Pancasila economic system would openly recognize the need for an appropriate degree
of
economic nationalism in a developing country such as Indonesia, both because domestic political
considerations demand a display of national independence and because domestic entrepreneurs are
unlikely to be able ever to compete successfully with either domestic Chinese firms or foreign
competitors unless they are given effective support for a period of consolidation.”
(5) “A balance would be found between decentralisation of economic decision making and strong
national
planning. On one hand, economic enterprises such as cooperatives would facilitate a high degree
of
decentralisation, but have the advantage that they are not the atomistic highly individualistic
units found in textbook liberal capitalist economies. On the other hand, strong national
planning is
also regarded as desirable. Former Communications Minister Frans Seda reflected the consensus
when
he said that in a Pancasila economic system “...the formulation of economic activity and
production
must be carried on with social supervision and evaluation so as to reflect economic democracy”
and
that “...economic production and planning institutions will be needed which allow for
representative
social participation in the planning process.”
The five pillars of Pancasila Economics, as outlined by McCawley (1982), paint a picture of a
system
seeking a middle ground. It avoids both the excesses of unfettered markets and rigid central
planning. Harmony and family principles (asas kekeluargan dan prinsip harmoni) guide economic
behavior, prioritizing collaboration over individual gain. Social and religious values are seen
as
motivators alongside economic incentives, fostering a sense of community and ethical conduct.
The
system prioritizes equitable social development, ensuring all Indonesians benefit from economic
growth. Nurturing a strong national economy involves a degree of economic nationalism,
particularly
during the development of domestic industries (infant industry protection). Finally, the
principle
of subsidiarity emphasizes empowering smaller entities to handle tasks they can manage
effectively.
If one were to summarize these five points in a few key words within modern economic language,
one
could also say that within a Pancasila economic system:
(1) Markets are tolerated, unless they fail, and the preferred economic actor is a cooperative.
(2) The idea of the human being is one who is guided by religious values.
(3) Inequitable social development is not tolerated.
(4) Indonesia’s development should start with infant-industry protection.
(5) A political structure in line with the principle of subsidiarity.
As Dick and McCawley (1982) correctly highlight, Mubyarto’s economic concerns are not uncommon.
In
fact, the entire history of economic thought is loaded with concerns towards unfettered market
liberalism. As an applied economist, Mubyarto should not be labeled with ideological jargons,
but as
someone who deeply cared for Indonesia’s equitable social development. Mubyarto was seeking for
a
“Third Way” to pure capitalism and socialism - a way that is not plastered with ideological
cobble
stones, but technocratic ones.
For Mubyarto, practical, not ideological, matters mattered. As Dick and McCawley (1982)
highlight,
Pancasila Economics is particularly in need of solutions to the problems of equitable social
development, market power within existing economic structures, especially those exercised by
foreign
economic actors, corruption, and the development of a domestic entrepreneurial class. These are
all
concerns, which are quite universal to newly developing countries and which cannot be
effectively
addressed within an ideological debate, but only a practical policy dialogue.
Unfortunately, concrete economic policy advice is absent in Mubyarto’s writings. Liddle (1982)
notes, that after “several readings of Mubyarto’s writings and others’ commentaries, it is
unclear to me in what sense this amalgam of received ideas (e.g., capitalism always means that
“the strong drive out the weak”), romanticism (the village is still the locus of the true
Indonesian gotong royong personality), moral appeal (if we act like our idealised ancestors all
will he well), and straightforward advice to economic planners (decentralise) constitute an
“economic system”. And to be fair, Mubyarto himself has not made grandiose claims for his ideas.
Still, it is a fact that his Ekonomi Pancusila was for the first nine months of 1981 a major
centre of media attention and debate among Indonesia’s intelligentsia. Why?”
Liddle (1982, p. 99) also provides a possible explanation, which he sees in a contrast “between
the political strength and popular weakness or Bappenas economic doctrine, on the one hand, and
the popular strength and political weakness of the nationalist and Islamic ideological
traditions, on the other.” Mubyarto’s writings on Pancasila economics then became a platform for
oppositionists to safely articulate their discontent with Suharto’s regime.
In sum, by the 1980s, Pancasila Economics had been instrumentalized by two sides. Politically,
Suharto tried to frame it according to his guided top-down capitalist ideas. Sincere
ideologically unbiased attempts to advance Pancasila Economic as a discipline were hijacked by
political oppositionists to Suharto. During his career, Mubyarto had found himself regularly
between a rock and a hard place.
In this regard, Liddle (1982, p. 100) notes that: “To understand the significance of Mubyarto’s
Ekonomi Puncasila it is important to be aware that he straddles the nationalist (including at
least for purposes of temporary political convenience the young Muslim intellectuals) and New
Order camps. In my judgement, his critics have concentrated too much on the Sukarnoist resonance
and “economic system” aspects of Ekonomi Pancasila and not enough on the intellectual and
political bridging role which he appears to be trying to play within the system. [...] But they
miss what I judge to be an important part of Mubyarto’s purpose, which is to employ some
powerful political symbols (those obsolete nationalist ideas) plus contemporary academic
theories to lobby for certain major changes (not all of which fit the standard nationalist
paradigm).”
Since the reform period, Pancasila Economics as an independent research discipline has lost
momentum. Since the 1990s, no major economically holistic academic thrust seems recognizable.
While publications with a Pancasila Economic reference are still being generated, their focus is
widely scattered around topics such history, education, and intellectual influences. A focus on
how to implement a Pancasila Economic system in terms of principles of economic policy is still
largely absent.
Since 2017, Indonesia has celebrated Pancasila Day on June 1, the day when Sukarno gave his
“Lahirnya Pancasila” (Birth of Pancasila) speech in 1945. Then President Jokowi, the new
holiday’s initiator, called on all Indonesians to embrace the Pancasila values, leaving some
Indonesians uncomfortable. Eventually, Suharto, while not officially celebrating Pancasila with
a holiday, put a lot of emphasis on indoctrinating Indonesia's school children with a detailed
set of specific items under each of the five Pancasila pillars.
Of course, there is a big difference between a public holiday and a school curriculum with the
first leaving much more room for open debate. It is probably safe to say that Jokowi’s intention
was to initiate such an open debate and to clean Pancasila from its reputation as being nothing
more than a vehicle for political instrumentalization. As the Jakarta Post in an editorial on
May 31, 2017 concludes, in response to a ban of the Islamic Hizbuth Tahrir Indonesia
organization on grounds of violating Pancasila, “efforts to ensure inclusiveness by reducing the
social economic gap, is a much better way to convince Indonesians why Pancasila should remain
the “cement” binding the archipelago.” A revival of Pancasila Economics with such a
socioeconomic objective and without any ideological labels would surely be a welcomed voice in
Pancasila Day celebrations.